COSTS OF PRODUCTION
Derivatives and Optimization
© 2011, Kwan Choi.
Since marginal concepts are ubiquitous in most economic problems, we consider derivatives in this note. You have been exposed to the derivatives already. You are familiar with the notions of marginal costs, marginal products, marginal utilities, etc. There are many derivative rules or formulas which you could learn from any calculus course. To get through the basic optimization concepts, we will consider the most widely used formula, the one for polynomials.
1. Derivatives of Polynomials
[pic]
2. Peculiar notations: X0 = 1 for any X.
We also write X1 as simply X when its exponent is 1.
Example: If the total cost is: [pic] then a is fixed cost and the remainder is the variable cost because the value of the three terms change as x changes. The slope of a function is called the derivative, and is often denoted by a prime (' ). The verb “differentiate” a function means to “take derivative” of that function with respect to its variable. For instance, if C denotes a cost function,
[pic]
then its marginal cost is the first derivative of the cost function, i.e.,
[pic]
You can also take a second derivative,
[pic]
If the second derivative is positive, it means that the slope is increasing (e.g., -3,- 2, -1, 0, 1, 2, 3) as x increases, and hence it has a minimum. If the second derivative is negative, the slope is declining (e.g., 3, 2, 1, 0, -1, -2, -3), it has a maximum.
Partial Derivatives
Sometimes there are two or more control variables to manipulate the objective function (profit function, utility function, cost function, etc.) If there are two variables, X and Y, it is necessary to distinguish the partial derivative with respect X and Y.
For instance, there are many consumption goods, it is necessary to distinguish marginal utilities of different goods. For instance, marginal utility of good 1 is the increment of utility attained from an extra unit of that good, holding the quantity of the other good (the quantities of all other goods) constant. Marginal utility of X1 is written as:
[pic]
[pic]
Note that units of measurement are arbitrary. Hence, marginal utilities of the same good can differ if the extra units are measured in gram or kilogram or pound. It is often useful to measure marginal utilities when the extra unit becomes extremely small, or infinitesimally small.
In Figure 14, marginal utility is the slope of the line AB. However, as ΔX becomes infinitesimally small or approaches zero, line AB approaches the tangent line AD. For practical reasons, it is safe to argue that marginal utility is the slope of the tangent line AD (at the consumption point A).
Marginal utilities are measured while all other goods are held constant. Thus, marginal utility of X is a partial derivative of U with respect to X. The quantities of all other goods are held constant.
[pic]
Example:
Let
[pic]
be the utility function.
A partial derivative with respect to X ignores all variables other than X and treat them as if they are constant.
Derive marginal utilities of X and Y when evaluated at X = 5, and Y = 7.
[pic] (1)
[pic] (2)
Derive the marginal utilities of X and Y when [pic]
[pic] (3)
[pic] (4)
Marginal Rate of Substitution
Along a given indifference curve, consumption of two goods can be changed without altering the utility level. This means that on an indifference curve, the change in utility is zero.
[pic]
The slope of the indifference curve is the ratio of marginal utilities:
[pic]
[pic]
In Figure 15, marginal rate of substitution (of x1 for x2) is the slope of the ray AB. However, here the change in good 1 (Δx1) is rather large. As Δx1 becomes infinitesimally small or approaches zero, the slope of line AB approaches the tangent line AD. Thus, for practical reasons, it is safe to say that MRS at point A is the slope of the indifference curve (at that point).
[pic]
Remark: As (q becomes infinitesimally small, Marginal Cost approaches the slope of the TC curve. Thus, MC is the slope of the TC or its derivative, [pic]
If the total cost curve is concave (before the inflexion point), C˝ < 0 and the cost increases at a decreasing rate.
If the total cost curve is convex (after the inflexion point), C˝ > 0, and the cost increases at an increasing rate.
At the inflexion point C˝ = 0.
[pic]
Global Minimum and Maximum
Global optimum occurs where f ′ = 0. In addition, the global minimum requires f ″ > 0, whereas the global maximum requires f ″ < 0.
[pic]
[pic]
Unconstrained maximization problem
The Single Variable Case
Choose x to maximize the objective function ((x).
The First Order Condition (FOC): The first derivative must be zero at the maximum or minimum,
[pic]
The Second Order Condition (SOC): The second derivative must be negative for a maximum, and positive for a minimum.
[pic]
Multivariate Case
Choose X and Y to maximize [pic]
The First order condition (FOC): Each partial derivative must be zero. That is,
[pic]
The Second order condition (SOC): Each second order derivative must be negative ([pic]), but also [pic] For a minimum, each second order derivative must be positive ([pic]), and [pic]If the latter condition is not satisfied, i.e., if [pic]then it is a saddle point. That is, the point that meets the first order conditions is neither a minimum nor a maximum.
[pic]
Example
Let
[pic] (5)
be a production function. Derive MRTS.
Along an isoquant, the output level is fixed, i.e., dY = 0. Totally differentiating (5), we get
[pic] (6)
where [pic] is marginal product of input i. Thus, the slope of an isoquant is
[pic] (7)
Note
[pic] (8)
[pic] (9)
Substituting (8) and (9) into (7), we get marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS) of capital (K) for labor (L):
[pic] (10)
Constrained Minimization Problem
The firm’s cost minimization problem is to choose K and L to
Minimize [pic](cost)
Subject to[pic] (output constraint)
The Lagrangian function associated with this problem can be written as:
[pic] (11)
The first order conditions are:
[pic] (12)
[pic] (13)
[pic] (14)
where the subscripts denote partial derivatives, i.e., [pic] and [pic]. From the two equations in (13) and (14), we get
[pic]
Rearranging this, we obtain
[pic] (15)
which is the equilibrium condition for cost minimization. Moreover, the value of the Lagrange multiplier in equilibrium is
[pic] (16)
That is, the Lagrange multiplier is marginal cost of production.
[pic]
Democracy and Tyranny
The Lagrange multiplier in a constrained optimization problem can be interpreted as the relative weight or trade-off between two or more competing goals. In the above example, marginal cost is the trade-off between output and cost. If there are two industries, efficiency is achieved when one industry’s revenue is maximized for any given revenue (or output) of the other industry. For instance, a country may maximize revenue of the private sector for given revenue (or output) of the military sector (resources are given). In this case, the Lagrangian problem is [pic] and ( is the weight assigned to the revenue in the defense sector. If ( = 0 or close to zero, it means that the society assigns a low weight to national defense, i.e., little or no money is spent on national defense.
Next, consider consumer welfare in a society that consists of two or more individuals or regions (Shiites, Kurds, and Sunnis, for example). The Lagrangian problem can be written as [pic] where x is consumption goods, and [pic] and [pic]are utilities of consumers 1 and 2, respectively. Intuitively, this problem maximizes the welfare of individual 1 while guaranteeing a minimum utility ([pic]) for individual 2. Of course, this minimum guaranteed utility level for individual or group 2 can be raised. This amounts to raising the value of (. The higher the minimum guaranteed level of utility, the larger the value of (.
In a society with more than two groups, the Lagrangian problem is to maximize group 1’s welfare, given that some minimum levels of utilities for group 2 and 3 are guaranteed. Thus, the Lagrangian problem is written as:
[pic]
where (i is the Lagrange multiplier for group i.
In extreme cases where (i is either zero or near zero, that man’s (or region’s) welfare is ignored. This is the case of dictatorship, tyranny or slavery. This shows that “if one man is to be absolutely free, then another must become an absolute slave.”(Urantia Book.) If domestic privacy must be guaranteed absolutely, then no phone calls of terrorists can be monitored. In a free market economy, the society often has two or more conflicting goals, in which case the society solves a constrained optimization problem, assigning different weights to conflicting goals.
When ( = 1 for all, the problem has a significant meaning in the society, because all individuals are assigned the same weights. “If one man craves freedom ( liberty ( he must remember that all other men long for the same freedom.” Thus, in an ideal society, all are given equal rights (or opportunities), and ( = 1 for all means democracy. In this case, the society maximizes [pic]
Democracy and the free market, of course, do not equalize incomes of all individuals, because individuals differ in their abilities, tastes or genetic endowments. Thus, in a free market where all consumers are treated equal, there will be income differences among individuals. Market economies make two adjustments. First, historical experiences show that extreme income inequality is a destabilizing factor in civilizations. Governments in a free market often recognize this problem and redistributes income from the rich to the poor by income tax. Second, criminals and underage individuals are not given the voting rights.
................
................
In order to avoid copyright disputes, this page is only a partial summary.
To fulfill the demand for quickly locating and searching documents.
It is intelligent file search solution for home and business.
Related download
- review of partial differtial operations
- calculus 3 final exam review spring 2009
- first order differentiation
- two dimensional first order partial differential equation
- costs of production
- chapter 10 multi variable functions
- derivation of the ordinary least squares estimator
- calculus 3 final exam review
- first order differential equations
Related searches
- calculation of production yield
- rising costs of higher education
- increasing costs of healthcare
- costs of owning a home
- costs of refinancing mortgage
- costs of online education
- hidden costs of buying a home
- personal costs of addiction
- costs of production definition economics
- costs of college
- costs of plastic surgery
- economic costs of production quizlet