Chapter 7: Public Goods PUBLIC GOODS
Chapter 7: Public Goods
Outline
Optimal provision of public goods.
Under-provision generally characterizes markets with public goods, absent government intervention.
Private sector provision. Crowd out Problems
OPTIMAL PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS
Pure public goods have two traits:
They are non-rival in consumption: The marginal cost of another person consuming the good is zero, and does not affect your opportunity to consume the good.
They are non-excludable: There is no way to deny someone the opportunity to consume the good.
Table 1 gives some examples.
If a IgcIcoeeocdcrreiesaambmoitsihsrraiivvlasaoll, abenexdclaueudxsacelbuTlmdeCha,SyIaibstobliemtslae,ebTxlegVcolsuioshddoanswboaslner-e,rixsv"aianmmlc,pepbuleterhecsea"oupcfsaupebulmeircey
cTboaenbcsalueums1peittiIoiscnaaonfpsirtivmparpetelcylgunodooetds.hyaorpuceguofombrmooliycmpcdoasgnnobsyoeucdmaspn,utisimsoeinmptuhoprefleyyitpraieunrfebunlsinoceowgntoa-royhivdoasol,,k cYFoeonOtrsitetuhximesarinmgicogopenolte-hcde,ersxeacsalcamurremdowa"eibmidtilchepeduybcoreseruiced".aaepumwusba.FeItlikTncidtsbNhaiisumsealaltyltisi,ntohaopinseunhadyuroelepapndsrp-teeihyvufoexa(buctntloselirsucyscedgsgotaoioemnsboomsldaeedu.s,scme.blxapetrsetceisonaibntcu)o.steh
goonorDlicdvylsaewelababreflyeycicfanvoaueruisrysnyeoedtughyifoetfoiuycprcuaoulertnetrosjorueipyvmmaroela,ehbniineotbutxniistidacsntmeooiapntmnl-eri.avpraIetlauieasxnirsncdelopunrdo-aprtniebv-ucleaetxle.bcbdleu,lcideacavuebsrlgey.oomneyods
pereddeusctremiadanakssefermoxcmolrueudspiaciebnedlgece.trsheteraiamsni.dseawclsaooln"kcs.ounmsputmioenso" fthnaattipornoatel dcteiofenn.se
use the same sidewalk. proItesctiotnhdeoesgnootoddiminrisihvyaolurin ccoonsnusmuptimon poftiti. on?
Yes
No
Yes
Ice cream
Cable tv
Is the good No
excludable
?
Crowded city sidewalk
National defense
Optimal Provision of Private Goods
Consider a private good, like ice cream. Figure 1 shows the market for ice cream
cones, assuming that the alternative use of the money is buying cookies at $1 each. This makes cookies the numeraire good.
1
Price of ice cream
$3
$2
At a AprdBiAcdedeinndogihnfuag$ps3u,BapnneBeniien'tshnde'iasvrnidapduneJadresl,Jorrenyr'rsy's dJedemionrrwadyninviadnwidlsdsauiomvradihldu-aduscselhaomlapidcnianengimncddrdsaeienvaamditmdsaeu.ngaadiclv,he dporiwcecnuswgoriavvcereidesf-tosysr'losoicpcdeiieentcgmyr'edasaendmmde.amntad$n3d..
S=SMC
cAutraveprfiocreicoef A$c2rdLe,deabianmodgt.ihnugpetBooepanle'csoamnpdeJtietirvrey's
demand meoqrueinilidcbierviiudcmrueaalmtd$e.2m. aBnedns g&ivJeerry
conssoucmietey'dsifdfeermenaTtnhqdeuaraetn$tisi2ti.easm. arket supply curve
associated with producing ice
cream.
DJERRY 0 QJERRY QBEN QTOTAL
DBEN
Figure 1 Demand for a private good
SMB =DBEN+JERRY
Quantity of ice cream
Optimal Provision of Private Goods
In this figure, as price adjusted, each person changed his quantity consumed.
For a private good, consumers demand different quantities at the same market price.
We can also represent this relationship mathematically. Ben has preferences over cookies (C) and ice cream (IC):
U B (C, IC)
( ) As does Jerry:
U J C, IC
Optimal Provision of Private Goods
Utility maximization requires that each of
their indifference curves is tangent to the
budget constraint. Moreover, suppliers set
P=MC. For Ben, we have:
MU
B IC
MUCB
= MRSIBC,C
=
PIC PC
=
MCIC MCC
For Jerry we have:
MU
J IC
MU
J C
= MRSIJC,C
=
PIC PC
=
MCIC MCC
Optimal Provision of Private Goods
The private market equilibrium in this case is socially efficient.
The MRS for any quantity of ice cream equals the SMB of that quantity?the marginal value to society equals the marginal value to any individual in the perfectly competitive market.
2
Optimal Provision of Public Goods
Now consider the tradeoff between a public good, like missiles, and a private good like cookies.
Figure 2 shows the market for missiles, assuming that the alternative use of the money is buying cookies at $1 each.
Price of missiles
$6
$4 $3 $$22 $1
AddAindgdiunpg BupenB'sena'nsdaJnedrrJye'srry's wiwlliinllignngensesstsotopapyagyivfoerseach
soqciueatyn'tsitydegmivaensdsofocrie1tym'sisdseilme.and. As does Jerry.
There is a market supply curve
Leading to a competiAtivadesdsinogciautpedBewni'tsh apnroddJuecrirnyg's
BdeenmhWBeaaqneshJudniefaliDo'elcsrirbrduJyJwErtorfheiRivcuiwrlRereslomriYnntynffwi'mgosrassnarutiwtsermm5dmssileiimlsslsiienssltitoshgsoiilspiseenlepiise$nlsea.s2igwassys.mi.$lftlodioe4Bnre.gepQmthnna.aeey&nssd
tompisasyilegsives society's for the 5th missSi=leS. MC
WBehnil'es Jweilrlriny'gsnwesillsintgonpeasys ftoor pthaey
for tfhifethfimfthismsiliessisile$1is. $2.
DBEN
SMB=DBEN+JERRY
0
1
5
Figure 2 Demand for a public good
Quantity of missiles
Optimal Provision of Public Goods
Unlike the case of private goods, where aggregate demand is found by summing the individual demands horizontally, with public goods, aggregate demand is found by summing vertically.
That is, holding quantity fixed, what is each person's willingness to pay?
Optimal Provision of Public Goods
We can also represent this relationship
mathematically. Ben has preferences over
( ) cookies (C) and missiles (M): U B C, M
To Ben, the marginal missile is worth
( ) MU
B M
MU
B C
=
MRS
B M
,C
Jerry's preferences are U J C, M
To Jerry, the marginal missile is worth
MU
J M
MU
J C
=
MRS
J M
,C
3
Optimal Provision of Public Goods
The social marginal benefit (SMB) of the next
missile is the sum of Ben and Jerry's marginal
rates
of
substitution:
MRS
i M
,C
where "i" represents eaich person in society.
Efficiency requires
i
M
RS
i M
,C
=
MCM MCC
Optimal Provision of Public Goods
That is, social efficiency is maximized when the marginal costs are set equal to the sum of the marginal rates of substitution (rather than each individual's MRS).
This is because the good is non-rival. Since a unit can be consumed by all consumers, society would like the producer to take into account all consumers' preferences.
PRIVATE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS: Private-sector Underprovision
In general, the private sector underprovides public goods because of the free rider problem.
Consider two people, Ben and Jerry, and two consumption goods, ice cream and fireworks.
Set the prices of each good at $1, but fireworks are a public good. Assume that Ben and Jerry have identical preferences.
Private-sector Underprovision
Ben and Jerry benefit equally from a firework that is provided by either of them.
What matters is the total amount of fireworks.
Each person chooses combinations of ice cream and fireworks in which his own MRS equals the ratio of price.
For both Ben and Jerry, they set:
MRS F,IC = 1, MU IC = MU F
Whereas optimal provision requires:
MRS
i F
,
IC
=1
i
4
Private-sector Underprovision
With identical preferences, the optimal condition is:
2
MU F MU IC
= 1,
which
implies
MU F
=
MU IC 2
Recall that marginal utilities diminish with increasing consumption of a good.
In this example, optimal provision would require that fireworks are consumed until their utility equals half the marginal utility of ice cream.
Thus, each individually buys too much ice cream privately.
The Free Rider Problem in Practice
There are some interesting examples of the freerider problem in practice.
Only 7.5% of public radio listeners in New York contribute to the stations?that is, there is a lot of freeriding. In the United Kingdom, the BBC charges an annual licensing fee for all television owners.
Many users of file sharing services never contribute uploaded files; they only download files. Some of these services, like Kazaa, give download priority to those who contribute.
When Is Private Provision Likely to Overcome the Free Rider Problem?
Under what circumstances are private market forces likely to solve the free rider problem?
Intense preferences. Altruism. Utility from one's own contribution to the public
good.
Some individuals care more than others
When some individuals have especially high demand for a public good, private provision may emerge (but not necessarily provide efficiently ? in particular, the public good is still likely to be underprovided).
The key intuition is that the decision to provide a public good is a function of the enjoyment that the individual gets from the total amount of the public good, net of cost.
If a person gets a lot of enjoyment, or has a lot of money, he will choose to purchase more of the public good even though it benefits others.
5
................
................
In order to avoid copyright disputes, this page is only a partial summary.
To fulfill the demand for quickly locating and searching documents.
It is intelligent file search solution for home and business.
Related download
- cp economics http 11243709 economics eoct
- chapter 7 public goods public goods
- public goods examples
- test economics quizlet page 1 of 8
- lecture 8 public goods harvard university
- econ 230a public economics lecture public goods
- public goods externalities
- 131 undergraduate public economics emmanuel saez uc
- chapter 14 externalities market failure and public
- microeconomics topic 9 explain externalities and public
Related searches
- define public goods in economics
- because public goods are quizlet
- public goods market failure example
- public goods company review
- public goods lifetime membership
- public goods problem
- because public goods are
- public goods definition economics
- public goods and services
- public goods membership
- public goods review
- examples of public goods quizlet