The Student Loan Consolidation Option
[Pages:42]Working Paper Series Congressional Budget Office
Washington, D.C.
THE STUDENT LOAN CONSOLIDATION OPTION: AN ANALYSIS OF AN EXOTIC FINANCIAL DERIVATIVE
Deborah Lucas Northwestern University and National Bureau of Economic Research
E-mail: d-lucas@kellogg.northwestern.edu Damien Moore
Congressional Budget Office E-mail: damien.moore@
April 2007 Working Paper 2007-05
The authors wish to thank John Kolla and Marvin Phaup for help and comments on this project. Lucas gratefully acknowledges support from the Searle Foundation. Working papers in this series are preliminary and are circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. They are not subject to CBO's formal review and editing processes. The analysis and conclusions expressed in them are those of the authors and should not be interpreted as those of the Congressional Budget Office. References in publications should be cleared with the authors. Papers in this series can be obtained at publications.
Abstract The federal government makes subsidized federal financing for higher education widely available. The extent of the subsidy varies over time with interest rate and credit market conditions. A loan provision that adds considerably to the size and volatility of the subsidy is the consolidation option, which allows students to convert floating-rate federal loans to a fixed rate equal to the average floating rate on their outstanding loans. We develop a model to estimate the option's cost and to evaluate its sensitivity to changes in program rules, economic conditions, and borrower behavior. We model borrower behavior using data from the National Student Loan Data System, which provides new insights on the responsiveness of consumers to financial incentives.
2
1. Introduction The federal student loan program makes low-cost federal financing for higher education
widely available. Because legislation rather than market forces determines federal student loan terms, the extent to which these loans are subsidized varies over time with interest rate and credit market conditions. Comparison of rates charged on private student loans with rates charged on federal loans suggests a typical differential of several percentage points annually. From an economic perspective, imperfections in private credit markets and legal limitations on selling human capital forward might justify subsidizing credit for education, although the effectiveness of such policies is controversial.1 In any case, one would expect an efficient subsidy to either reduce credit rationing or lower the cost of educational investment for target populations. Although the federal student loan program has these aspects,2 it also contains costly provisions that are hard to justify on efficiency grounds.
One apparently inefficient provision is the consolidation option, an exotic financial derivative created by a few paragraphs in the Higher Education Act. It allows students to convert their floating-rate loans to a fixed rate equal to the average floating rate on their outstanding loans. For some borrowers, it also allows maturity extension.
The consolidation option is of interest for several reasons. For one, it represents a multibillion-dollar public expenditure that has gone largely unmeasured and therefore has received little scrutiny. In addition, the benefits are distributed randomly across different cohorts of students, depending on interest rate conditions, rather than being distributed to help a target population. The consolidation option also demonstrates how the combination of programmatic complexity and the rules of federal budgeting can make it difficult to infer the full economic cost
1
See, for example, De Fraja (2002), Dynarski (2002), Edlin (1993), Hanushek (1989), and Keane (2002). Gale
(1991) points out that many federal credit programs probably have a small real effect on the allocation of credit, in
many cases simply crowding out private borrowing and lending.
2
Further, legislation exempting student loans from dismissal in bankruptcy may alleviate market imperfections
caused by restrictions on forward contracting of human capital.
3
of federal credit programs. Further, it provides a new setting in which to study how consumers respond to financial incentives and how their responses vary with the size of an incentive.
Recent legislation fixed the rate on new Stafford loans at 6.8 percent starting in July 2006 and made other changes that significantly lowered the value of the consolidation option for loans originated in July 2006 or later. The option is still valuable, however, on outstanding loans originated before that date. Consolidation may also reemerge as an issue if future legislation reinstates floating rates.
In this study, we develop an options pricing model to estimate the cost of the consolidation option and to evaluate the sensitivity of that cost to changes in rules and economic conditions. The model takes into account borrower behavior, program rules, the stochastic properties of interest rates, default, and the market price of risk. More broadly, the analysis demonstrates how modern options pricing methods can better inform public policy.3 As far as we know, this is the first academic study to address consolidation and these surrounding issues.4
Data from the National Student Loan Data System (NSLDS) from the Department of Education is used to study borrower behavior and to calibrate the behavioral assumptions embedded in the valuation model. The data suggest that students respond to the time-varying incentives to consolidate with much higher rates of consolidation in years when the option is most valuable.5 Further, interest rate sensitivity increases with the amount of debt outstanding. There is
3
For example, Falkenheim and Pennacchi (2003), Lucas and McDonald (2006), and Pennacchi and Lewis
(1994) also use option pricing methods to determine the value of government liabilities.
4
A study by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO, 2006) also examines the cost of the consolidation option.
This paper differs from that study in that this paper uses a more complex interest rate model to better account for
historic interest rate conditions and dynamics; uses previously unavailable student loan consolidation data to improve
estimates of consolidation choice and to integrate that choice more formally into the valuation model; and explicitly
formalizes the valuation model. This paper also provides specific estimates of consolidation costs for program years
1998 and 2005 and compares those estimates with a simulated distribution of consolidation costs based on information
available in 1998.
5
Although many recent studies have provided evidence of suboptimal financial behavior by individuals, few
have reported on whether inefficiency decreases with the amount at stake. An exception is Calvet, Campbell, and
Sodini (2006), who find more efficient portfolio allocations on the part of wealthier households in Swedish data.
4
some evidence of learning, because take-up rates have increased steadily over time even after controlling for interest rate incentives.
The pricing-model estimates reveal that the consolidation option has at times been extremely valuable. For instance, options exercised in 2004 had an intrinsic value of about $8.8 billion. Although the cost in some years was much lower than in the recent past, the analysis suggests that the possibility of high costs might have been foreseen.
From a policy perspective, the subsidy is likely to be an inefficient mechanism to encourage investment in education. It has little effect ex ante on the perceived cost of borrowing, confers benefits randomly across different cohorts of borrowers ex post, and provides the largest benefits to professional students graduating from high-tuition schools--those likely to have the best access to unsubsidized capital markets. The lack of transparency surrounding the cost of the option, however, has reduced its visibility to policymakers.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 briefly describes the federal student loan program and the consolidation option. Section 3 outlines the options pricing model and critical modeling assumptions. Probit analysis of data from the NSLDS summarizes consolidation take-up rates and their sensitivity to borrower characteristics and market conditions. Section 4 discusses both historical and forward-looking cost estimates. Section 5 discusses policy implications and conclusions. Appendices A and B contain more-detailed descriptions of the options pricing model, supporting assumptions, and the statistical analysis of borrower behavior.
5
2. The Federal Student Loan Program The federal student loan program is one of the largest credit programs operated by the
U.S. government. In 2004, about 7.7 million students borrowed $55 billion in new federally backed loans, adding to the $432 billion in outstanding federal student loans.6 This was up from $126 billion in outstanding loans in 1998, reflecting the rapid growth of education costs and strong appetite for consumer debt during that period.
The government makes credit available through two similar but competing student loan programs--the Federal Direct Student Loan (DL, or direct loan) program, and the older Federal Family Education Loan (FFEL, or guaranteed loan) program. In the former, the government lends funds directly to qualifying students. In the latter, it guarantees loans originated by private lenders against losses from default and pays lenders any shortfall between the rate charged to students and a promised minimum.7 Schools have a choice of which program to adopt. Loan terms vary with the purpose of the loan; there are loans for undergraduates, graduate students, various types of professional students, and parents. Some students qualify for more highly subsidized loans on the basis of income. The terms offered to a given borrower are generally quite similar under the direct and guaranteed programs. Those loan terms--interest rates, maturity, loan limits, and so forth--are set by statute under the Higher Education Act.
Most loans made under the direct and guaranteed programs are Stafford loans, and these are the focus of our analysis. On Stafford loans originated between October 1998 and July 2006, students pay a variable interest rate based on a three-month Treasury rate that resets annually, plus a spread. The spread varies with the repayment status of the loan: It equals 1.7 percentage points when the student is in school, in the six-month grace period after leaving school, or in
6
About 10 percent of the total federal loan portfolio is loans to parents made under the Parent Loans for
Undergraduate Students (PLUS) program.
7
Currently, the student rate in repayment is the three-month Treasury rate plus 2.3 percentage points, whereas
the rate guaranteed to lenders is the three-month commercial paper rate plus 2.34 percentage points.
6
periods of deferment and equals 2.3 percentage points otherwise.8 The interest rate is capped at 8.25 percent.
2.1 The Consolidation Option The consolidation option has three main features. First, it allows borrowers to combine
one or more outstanding loans into a new loan. Second, borrowers pay a fixed interest rate on the consolidation loan equal to a weighted average of the rates prevailing on the loans they consolidate. This option to switch a loan from a floating rate to a fixed rate is termed a "swaption" in financial markets. Third, some borrowers have an extension option, which allows them to extend the maturity of their loans beyond what is otherwise permitted.9 Borrowers have the opportunity to consolidate loans for as long as their original Stafford loans remain outstanding. They can also reconsolidate their previously consolidated loans with new Stafford loans, but the new fixed interest rate that the borrower obtains is a weighted average of the fixed rates on the previously consolidated loans and the floating rate on the original loans. Thus, borrowers have the valuable right to lock in the floating rate on each original loan only once.10
Consolidation also affects government costs through the program rules that govern payments to guaranteed lenders, because consolidation lowers the guaranteed rate of return to
8
For "subsidized" Stafford loans, which account for approximately 50 percent of the value of outstanding
Stafford loans, borrowers pay no interest while they are in school, in grace or in other periods of payment deferment.
The subsidized share of new loans is declining and is expected to continue to decline.
9
Borrowers in the direct program with loans originated between 1998 and 2006 receive little incremental
benefit from the extension option, as they can extend loan maturity on their direct Stafford loans with or without
consolidating. Many borrowers in the guaranteed program benefit from the extension option, because only borrowers
with balances above $30,000 can extend their loans without also consolidating. Consolidation allows all borrowers to
extend their repayment period according to the rules governing the direct program. (After June 2006, the extension
rules for the direct program are the same as for the guaranteed program.)
10
Students who have not exhausted their loan limits can lower their borrowing rate further by taking new
student loans to pay off older consolidation loans in favorable interest rate conditions.
7
lenders by 0.75 percentage points annually,11 and because lenders pay a small fee to the government at the time of consolidation. The cost saving to the government from lower fees paid is partially offset by the longer maturity of some consolidation loans and, historically, by the presence of a rate floor on lender payments.
2.2 Benefits to Students The consolidation option provides students with several distinct benefits--an interest rate
option, an extension option, and a liquidity benefit of lower monthly payments for some borrowers. Guaranteed lenders also advertise the convenience of a single bill each month.
Perhaps the greatest benefit to students comes from the interest rate option. For a given maturity, the market rate on a floating-rate loan is generally lower than the corresponding fixed rate because yield curves tend to slope upward. By being allowed to convert a floating rate into a long-term fixed rate, students often can lock in a favorable spread. Conversely, when floating rates are high, students can choose to defer consolidation. Hence, the floating-to-fixed-rate conversion option has significant value, but that value diminishes as the loan amortizes.
The term extension is also of value for qualifying borrowers in the guaranteed program. Stafford loans allow students to borrow at a below-market rate of interest.12 Market rates on private student loans, a market that has grown rapidly and has become increasingly competitive in recent years, provide an indication of the fair market rate for government-sponsored student loans.13 The annual interest subsidy is then the difference between the estimated fair market rate
11
Lenders receive a special allowance payment equal to the rate on three-month commercial paper (CP) plus
2.34 percentage points for Stafford loans, plus any floor income (a payment when rates fall below a floor on loans
issued prior to June 2006). Consolidation lenders get CP + 2.64 - 1.05 = CP + 1.59. The difference is at least 0.75
percentage points and may be higher at times due to a rate floor.
12
This is true even of "unsubsidized" Stafford loans. The government's measure of subsidy cost for budgeting
does not include administrative costs or a charge for market risk, causing reported costs to be systematically lower than
a market-value-based measure of opportunity cost (CBO, 2004).
13
Private lenders offer rates that vary with a borrower's credit score and educational institution. To the extent
that private loans are taken disproportionately by professional students (e.g., law, medicine, business), they may not be
representative of the average Stafford loan credit quality.
8
................
................
In order to avoid copyright disputes, this page is only a partial summary.
To fulfill the demand for quickly locating and searching documents.
It is intelligent file search solution for home and business.
Related download
- the ins and outs of student loan refinancing and
- should i consolidate or rehabilitate my federal student loan
- msu mankato federal loan consolidation info
- the student loan consolidation option
- student loan repayment and consolidation
- student loan consolidation scams service problems
- debt consolidation sample letters for free
Related searches
- student loan consolidation companies
- student loan consolidation programs
- best student loan consolidation programs
- federal student loan consolidation forms
- private student loan consolidation lenders
- government student loan consolidation program
- direct student loan consolidation application
- federal student loan consolidation calculator
- federal student loan consolidation form
- federal student loan consolidation rates
- private student loan consolidation rates
- student loan consolidation estimate