With today’s communication and media connections, some ...



Global Processes, Local Systems

E. Paul Durrenberger

2003

Urban Anthropology Vol 32(3-4):253-279

Abstract

I analyze factors at work in the global political-economic system to situate ethnographic treatments of local processes. After showing how the classic upward spiral of capitalist development can turn into a downward spiral, I analyze the relationships among interest rates, government borrowing, social programs, inflation, jobs, taxes, foreign loans, prices of export and import goods to show how their interactions result in a quasi-random system. I show how finance gains power over productive capital in this system and how this contributes to global randomness so that we can understand these processes without being able to predict them with any degree of accuracy.

Key Words: globalization, political economy, finance, random systems, complexity.

Global Processes, Local Systems

Humanity has been awash in global flows since we started walking, but they became exponentially faster with boats and printing, then with airplanes and telegraphs, and now with electronic, fiber optic and wireless networks and computer technology. Nowadays cultural artifacts move across the planet at the speed of light. Pálsson and I (1996) asked how such categories as ethnicity and nation are generated, what are the economic and political realities that lead to ethnic cleansing, mass rape, and homicidal and suicidal terror and war. Rather than asking why people were willing to die and kill for ethnic notions such as nations, we proposed asking what the alternatives are for the people in those landscapes, what interests they contest, who defines the issues and alternatives and by what means, what power, and what relationships stand behind and ratify that power. In this paper, I want to take another step toward answering some of these questions.

As in the past, the challenge to ethnography in the post-modern age is to locate relevant systems, understand their components and relations, and the people in them without giving up the strengths of classical anthropology (Durrenberger and Pálsson 1996). The information revolution makes possible networks of relationships based on global markets for capital. This in turn enables corporations to invest in distant lands to integrate productive processes as intramural transactions. This defines supra-national levels of technical and economic organization that dis-articulate rather than integrate local, regional and national economic systems, the bases of governmental control. These processes alter social relationships and cultural representations, undermine local bases of social cohesion, and make local politics and economic systems less relevant. The bases of identity and livelihood change with the dislocations of people, wealth and relations of production and power. The chaotic and quasi-random global flux of culture and cultures based on the new technologies and economic and political realities is one foundation of post-modern ideologies and theories.

This article is not ethnographic. It is an attempt to understand the relationships among parts of the global system, why they are chaotic and quasi-random, and how that affects what we do as anthropologists. I start with a theoretical discussion, move to a description of the complexities of a chaotic global system, and then discuss ethnographic consequences. While my discussion of the complexities of the global system is abstract, I return in the third section to concrete ethnographic examples.

The subject matter may be somewhat frustrating because it does not entail linear relationships—ones in which results are proportional to causes—double the input, double the output. Such relationships are highly structured. At the other end of the continuum of structure to non-structure is the lack of relationship or structure that we call randomness. Structures that we can understand in terms of deterministic relationships but which are so complex and irregular that we cannot predict them to any extent are chaotic. Chaos theory is the attempt to describe and understand such systems. Such systems are deterministic, but sensitive to their starting points or initial conditions. Slight differences at any time can lead to can lead to very different end end-results. Some systems are so sensitive that we cannot measure the variables sufficiently accurately to predict their trajectories.

Some of the relationships are self-intensifying. An increase in the value of one variable causes an increase in the value of another. The increase in the second variable in turn causes an increase in the first. The classic example is the population of dividing organisms such as yeast. An increase in population causes an increase in progeny which causes an increase in population. The more yeast there are, the more they make. So the population of yeast is self-intensifying, characterized by an exponentially rising curve. No such exponential curve is sustainable. Self-intensifying systems cause their own collapse.

The more yeast, the more their waste-products—alcohol—until they poison their environment and all die. So in this paper I shall discuss chaotic systems, some of which entail self-intensifying processes, systems which are therefore not sustainable. They are not predictable, but they are understandable, and that is the objective of this paper.

It is increasingly clear that some of the important topics that anthropologists must understand are not accessible to our classic ethnographic approach. States and global systems are two of them. Because those are two of the central concerns of this paper, it is not very ethnographic. That does not mean that I advocate a retreat from ethnography, as I hope will be clear by the end of the essay, but I do advocate a supplement to ethnography.

Anthropological theory

Eric Wolf (1999) argued that understanding cultural forms is only half the task of anthropology. In addition to specifying ideologies in cultural terms, we must also know how these cultural forms engage with the material resources and organizational arrangements of the world they try to affect or transform. Wolf wrote his book (1999) to explore the connection between ideas and power because he thought that anthropologists have only rarely grappled with the ways cultural configurations articulate with the power that arranges the settings and domains of social and economic life, especially the allocation and use of labor. He points out the mutuality of culture and power—powerful people shape culture and culture defines realities, even for the powerful. His goal was to understand and analyze the ways the power relations that organize economic and political systems also shape how people make the world intelligible through their cultures and symbols. Like Sahlins (2000), he returns to the necessity for ethnographic treatments.

Hannerz (1996) suggests that anthropologists celebrate the vitality and resistance of the local and conceptualize globalization in terms of a relationship between global and local. He concludes that the central questions are, though, how to identify the component relationships of emergent social structures that may cover great distances and cross national boundaries and understand how these relationships are related to one another. That is the goal of this paper. I start with an observation of minor local results of global forces.

While I was studying union locals in Chicago, I heard a story of a raccoon hiding out under the porch of a suburban resident’s house and causing all manner of mayhem. The very next Sunday the there was a story about it in the Chicago Tribune (July 11, 1999). The Russian Ruble had collapsed with the collapse of the Russian banking system, and with it, the price of raccoon pelts. Illinois had been one of the top wild fur exporting states sending 80% of its 300,000 raccoon pelts every year to Russia. When the price of pelts dropped from $30 in the 80s to $15 in the 90s to $3, trappers quit. In 1997 Illinois issued 25,000 trapping licenses; in 1999 fewer than 4,500. With less trapping there were more raccoons--a population explosion--and the raccoons started looking for homes in the suburbs with the yuppies. This story has a happy ending. The trappers who got $4 for a pelt now can get $75 to remove a pesky raccoon from an attic and don’t have to skin the animal and prepare the pelt (Smallwood 1999).

Select any area—Thailand, Mexico, Korea, Japan, Mississippi, Alabama, Chicago, Iowa--select any topic--fisheries, agriculture, manufacturing, services, rural, urban--and similar global forces are at work.

With today’s communication and media connections, some anthropologists such as Appadurai (1996), focus on the global as an autonomous realm of experience. Appadurai discusses relationships among flows of persons, technologies, finance, information and ideology that animate global cultural systems. Ethnography, he suggests, must deal with the changing social, territorial and cultural reproduction of identities as groups migrate, regroup, construct and reconstruct their histories, and are no longer associated with localities. If ethnography produces thick descriptions of knowledge in locales, what of perspectives that transcend the local? Severing links among wealth, people and areas changes the basis for the reproduction of culture so the subject matter of cultural studies is the relationship between expression and economic, social, and political realities. Appadurai focuses on the imagination and suggests that to describe the role of imagination, ethnography must focus on the complex lives of individuals rather than on locales.

Appadurai (1996:27) calls our attention to "the facts of the modern world,” but struggles ambivalently with notions of causal relationships. Because he brings no empirical methods to bear he cannot draw any conclusions except to suppose that "our current theories of cultural chaos are insufficiently developed to be even parsimonious models . . . much less to be predictive theories . . . " (1996:47). That is, after all, not the point of chaos theory. It cannot predict. It can understand, it can explain, but it cannot predict because it is not possible to know all possible outcomes of all possible trajectories of all determining forces. That’s what chaos theory is about. The point is to understand how the complex components of systems interact, even if we cannot predict outcomes. Appadurai's quandary is a consequence of his postmodern ideology’s disdain for empirical methods.

Using Kroeber’s idea of the ecumene to designate an “interwoven set of happenings and products,” Hannerz (1996:7) asks how transnational connections in the organization of meanings and actions hang together. The impinging of previously separate populations and social structures on one another’s living conditions and the global flows of meanings challenge the idea of culture as a set of organic relationships among populations, areas, political organizations, languages and coherent assemblages of meanings--a notion that derives from nationalism. Cultures are not integrated wholes with edges. Different symbolic modes have different boundaries. Hall (1997) for instance, shows the different boundaries of political-military relations, bulk goods trading, prestige goods exchanges, and information in world systems.

Hannerz (1996) argues that thinking of culture as what we learn by participation in social life does not require borders. Writing against culture, he argues, is no help. He makes the case that understanding other people and cultures does not imply any disrespect for them. Thinking of culture as our internal representations of our everyday life, he argues, does require that we recognize that everyday processes generate even such seemingly obvious and axiomatically true ideas as individuality. The concept of individuality is itself not an observable fact of nature but rooted in our experience. Our experience is shaped and determined by historically given systems of relationships.

It has become commonplace to observe that like the people we study, anthropologists are afloat in a sea of global capital, labor, and images. But the commonplace is the subject of our discipline and it has become obvious that if we would understand people anywhere we need to understand these global processes and how they affect everyday lives.

I think this is the end result of a long process of our struggle to transcend the local to understand the details of our ethnographic observations. The trade and traders, mission and missionaries are peripheral in Malinowski’s (1922) work but focal in the Comaroffs’(1992). Leach (1954) did not write of Kachin villages but of the whole region as a means of understanding particular villages as well as larger geographic and temporal processes. Julian Steward thought in terms of even wider contexts. Consider his contemporary-sounding words published in 1963 as a foreword (vii) to F.K. Lehman’s study of Chin in Burma:

This larger context today obviously includes the many-faceted influences from the emerging world industrial culture—a complex that includes developing technology, mass production, increasing occupational specialization, greater transportational facilities and education, enhanced social mobility that arises from ever changing occupational specialization, and new ideologies that relate to the altered underpinnings of society. Such features are affecting all parts of the world. . . .

Wolf (1957) analyzed the characteristic forms of community life common to Java and Mesoamerica as consequences of colonial policy. Robert Murphy and Julian Steward (1956) showed how groups in Brazil and Canada developed similar forms in response to markets and suggested that the tendency for aboriginal peoples to give up their crafts to devote efforts to producing trade goods to obtain industrial goods is so regular that any departures would require special explanations. More recently Lucian Hanks (1972) described the dynamics of a Thai village in terms of global events, while Sidney Mintz’s (1985) understanding of the history of sugar is global in scope.

As greater economic and electronic integration affect social organization and culture, Wilk (1997) suggests that the core issue in globalization is the relationship between culture and economy. He argues that a myth blinds us. The myth is that there are natural integrated autonomous and bounded local cultural-social-economic-ethnic systems. The myth continues that outside forces have transformed these systems to create new cultural forms. This myth blinds us to how economic integration affects local groups so that we don’t link our local studies into an understanding of global processes. Instead, he argues, we maintain our romantic dichotomy between the local autonomous system and the impact from outside.

Blanton and Peregrine (1997) point to Malinowski’s understanding of a complex intergroup process from the perspective of one local system rather than as a system in itself. This set the stage for a wider failure of anthropologists to contribute to theories about extra-local systems.

When Julian Steward found that he could not understand Puerto Rico in terms of local ecological factors, he viewed extra-local interactions as another environment for the adaptation of households and communities but failed to develop any insights about the extra-local system itself. Blanton and Peregrine find that all such studies of economic analyses beyond local systems share the assumption that some features of any social formation may be consequences of interactions across local boundaries. They argue that the consequences of these interactions vary in time and place, but they avoid the assumption that sociocultural change is primarily a result of endogenous causal factors. They urge an understanding of the larger systems themselves rather than from the point of view of local systems.

Some made connections beyond locales via ecological understandings. Barth (1956) discussed the relationship between economic forms, ecological possibilities, ethnic identity, and political organization. Those interested in markets and economic transactions have shown how they cover great areas via periodic markets, traveling merchants, and relationships of credit. Skinner (1964. 1977) showed that the Chinese villages clustered within three miles of a market town formed a meaningful unit of kinship, marriage, and culture. These units themselves clustered around larger ones related through the literate elite. This example provided an apt illustration of central place theory.

Following Skinner, Smith (1984) discussed central place theory in her analyses of regional economic and political structures that global forces influence. She differentiated different market functions and sizes in her meticulous empirical study of the types and locations of Guatemalan rural markets to show the dynamic relations of regional systems that enmesh villages (Smith 1985). Others, (e.g. Appleby 1985) expanded these concepts of regional and central place analysis to different geographic areas. Greenwood (1973) analyzed the political and economic structures of what he called “peasant states,” to variations in communities and how they are related on the one hand to households and on the other to larger levels of organization. Small and Tannenbaum (1999) have expanded that view.

Winslow (1997) points out that anthropologists have been encountering structural adjustment programs in the field. This requires us to go beyond the organization of production, consumption and exchange at local and regional levels to include and understand national economies and their relations with global systems by attention to flows of peoples, goods and information.

Furthermore, global and national economic systems respond to various kinds of policies. We do not see the consequences of larger economic shifts in the short run of fieldwork. To understand local responses we must understand the past as well as the present because responses to global forces are rooted in relationships that have developed over long periods of time. Attention to local detail helps to explain the connections between the lives of people and global systems (Winslow 1997).

Because we find states at work in fields, fishing boats and local communities we have integrated them into our ethnographies. Because they transcend the local, we do not know states ethnographically. To bridge the gap between the abstract power of states and the concrete experience of states on the ground in local systems of relationships, Anderson (1981 [1991]) wrote of imagined communities. With national languages, nationalist ideologies, and media, states create communities of the imagination that no one ever experiences, notions of kindreds of related people, all one nation that transcend locales. Americans may have felt this kind of presentation most strongly in the wake of the attacks on the Pentagon and the World Trade Center of September 11, 2001.

Herzfeld (1993) analyzed how privileged bureaucrats develop attitudes of indifference in dealing with everyday problems of their national kinsmen of this imagined community. Scott (1985) showed how peasants and other underlings receive the ideological moves of elites to create rhetorics of justification and deliver them via religion, media, and schools. He argues that peasants are aware of the disjunctures between rhetoric and reality and vote with their feet in various forms of resistance. Investigating the history of the traditions of states—the pomp and ceremony and custom that “has always been and will always be” Hobsbawm and Ranger (1983) showed who invented these forms and traditions and for what purposes. They spoke of invented tradition. Indifference, resistance, invented tradition, are all conceptual moves to make visible the hand of the state that remains elusive to our observations of people in locales.

When Gísli Pálsson and I (Durrenberger and Pálsson 1996) were seeking to analyze modern Iceland we focused on images to understand the lived experience of people that anthropologists discover in the realities of local landscapes. We found Ingold’s (1993) metaphor of landscape useful. He argues that we construct identities from positions within a continuous field of ongoing relationships, each of which defines a unique point of view within the process. If we include only those who share the same vantage points, we create boundaries. Those who are within the boundary are similar; those who are not are different. Gísli Pálsson and I argued that ethnicities are not primordial natural groups, but consequences of affiliations in which identity is defined by patterns of mental representation—cultures.

Hannerz (1996) argues that the notion of identity within social fields that Wilk (1997) objects to as a blinding myth is a projection of states’ preoccupations with boundaries and borders. The notion that groups share different cultural blueprints suggests that landscapes are uniform but the people viewing them are different by virtue of their different cultural representations. Ingold (1992) suggests that our categories are fleeting and contingent on our purposes and what is useful in our landscapes.

The variety of purposes contributes to heterogeneity. Because purposes even in a single landscape can be varied, there is no consensus, as Anthony Wallace pointed out (1961). Just because people can make categories does not mean that we obsessively categorize the world as some of the ethnoscience literature suggests (Durrenberger and Morrison 1979). Insofar as we have insisted on consensus without measuring it, anthropological theorizing has reflected the state’s demand for homogeneity within boundaries. People in different rhetorical, political, work or everyday situations may appeal to different principles of classification and creatively invent new ones. If cognitive anthropology bored itself to death, as Keesing (1972) suggested in a premature obituary notice, it may be because it had not situated itself in the world of action and experience (Lave 1988).

In Iowa in the past, a pig grew up where it was born, ate corn the farmer produced, and died in a slaughterhouse not far away. Today, the semen of a non-resident boar inseminates a sow produced in a massive ‘multiplier’ unit to insure her genetic make-up. The sites for farrowing, nurseries, and finishing may be separated by a few yards, a few miles, or a few hundreds of miles. The pig may grow fat on corn and protein supplements from distant locales before being trucked to a slaughter house. The waste products of swine and pork production become toxic wastes rather than nutrients for crops. The boxed pork can go anywhere on the planet. The capital for these processes likewise may come from anywhere on the planet. The effects are local, but the locales are separated. To study these processes, Kendall Thu and I had to map out relations that took us well beyond the barn-yards where we are most comfortable with our ethnographic work (Durrenberger and Thu 1996a, 1997a).

The challenge was, and remains, how to bring ethnography to bear on such global issues as the international capital that has organized industrial swine production in Thailand and Mexico as well as Utah, Iowa, Oklahoma, Texas and North Carolina. We see the local consequences in the demise of independent farmers across the Middle West (Durrenberger and Thu 1996a,1996b), the pollution of ground and surface water (Durrenberger and Thu 1994a, 1994b), and the corruption of political systems (Durrenberger and Thu 1994b, 1997b).

Manufacturing moves to those places that promise low costs for taxes, labor and regulation. If one place enacts or enforces environmental laws, the facility moves to one without such burdens. Smithfield moves its pork production unit from Virginia to North Carolina (Barboza 2000, Durrenberger and Thu 1997a, 1997b); General Motors moves auto production from Michigan to Mexico. As the industrial sector wanes in the Northern Hemisphere, the service sector waxes. With an international market for labor, the unions that organized labor locally lose influence in the process. Here, even more than in fisheries and agriculture, it is clear that national polices and international relations define local conditions. Unions try to regain political and market influence by organizing service employees including public workers. When they organize public workers effectively, agencies privatize the work; when they organize the private sector, corporations hire temps or move the work to other locales. But, like ethnography, unions have been rooted in local conditions and processes (Durrenberger and Erem 1997a, 1997b, 1999a, 1999b, 2000, Durrenberger 1997).

Like the locales we study ethnographically, unions are tied by invisible but powerful relationships to states by law, policy, practice, and political maneuver. If anthropologists have not developed theories of states, sociologists have them to spare. Bonnano and Constance (1996) classify these as those theories that cast the state 1) as an instrument of the capitalist class, 2) as an institution with some autonomy from capitalist domination, 3) as an autonomous institution, and 4) as an institution that is a mix of instrumentalist and autonomous roles.

The first asserts either that 1) because bureaucrats are of the ruling class, they are bound to that class through socialization, or 2) that the capitalist class exercises control over the state by means of its control over the economy. The second, relative autonomy view, holds that the state balances the accumulation of capitalists on the one hand with the state’s legitimation of itself via ideology and allocation of resources to other class interests on the other while maintaining relative autonomy from class interests. The third, autonomy view, follows Weber that the state maintains its own agenda and interests apart from the capitalist class or any other. Bonanno and Constance favor the fourth, mixed approach. Capitalism is not possible without state participation because the state maintains the conditions for the reproduction of capital. But the state mediates other interests to legitimate itself. The state in this view is not autonomous because it is dependent for its resources on accumulation through economic growth.

Accustomed to thinking of non-state systems and different kinds of states and economies, anthropologists will note the short-term nature of these sociological representations because they all center on the role of states in capitalist systems. When we add a historic dynamic of globalization that expands commodity relations around the planet (Wolf 1997), we see that the conditions of accumulation and the roles of states continuously change as different kinds of political and economic roles rise and fall at different times and in different places. With the globalization of production, some owners of capital pressure those sates that have maintained conditions favorable for capital by controlling labor and protecting capital to adopt protectionist measures while others push in other directions.

By the late 1960s to remain competitive in the global manufacturing system American multinational corporations had to decrease the price of their goods by either increasing productivity or finding some other way to reduce costs. Many focused on reducing the cost of labor by a sustained attack on organized labor (Gottschalk 2000) or by exporting jobs to third world countries that offered plentiful low cost female labor for labor intensive manufacturing processes in textiles, garments, shoes, toys and electronics. European countries were protected by tariff barriers and inexpensive migrant labor as well as access to the cheap labor of North Africa, the Mediterranean, and Ireland. Japanese corporations increased productivity by revamping manufacturing methods and increasingly used low cost labor in Taiwan, South Korea, Thailand, and Malaysia (Wilson 1992).

Some countries tried to become self sufficient by producing locally products that they were importing—import substitution. In Latin America, industrial workers organized to demand a share of the fruits of industrialization. They joined with growing urban middle classes and the influxes of rural migrants to produce populist movements. These countries were not attractive to corporations that were looking for places to assemble goods for re-export. Corporations wanted a labor force that either did not expect or could not demand an increasing share of the wealth they created. Hong Kong, Taiwan, Singapore and South Korea maintained authoritarian control over their middle classes and workers, often with direct military and police assistance from the U.S. (Wilson 1992).

Thus, the policies of different states created different environments, more or less attractive to multi-national corporations. National trade policies exposed first-world corporations to competition or protected them from it. As the global system expanded the role of states changed, sometimes quickly. Where there were few linkages among the productive activities of a locale there was no integrated economy that state policy could control. When states had to approach the World Bank for loans, they lost control of their economic policies.

So, as Bonanno and Constance (1996) point out, there is no single role for states. Some set the rules, others adapt to the consequences. The overall trend has been toward the development of other sources of power besides states and the redistribution of power within them. Corporations have waxed and many states have waned. Some speak of Fordism, often coupled with Taylorism, the development of manufacturing by the separation of management from work and the differentiation of manufacturing into minute single processes that management coordinates. Some speak of the alternatives to the vertical integration of manufacturing that developed as post-Fordism. All agree that there is a global system that incorporates and transcends locales and states.

How does this system work?

The reason the global system is chaotic and not given to prediction is that the forces are complex and contradictory. For instance, we cannot specify a single set of functions for all states. States gain influence. States lose influence. American foreign policy sets the stage for oppression of labor in Asian lands. Asian lands offer opportunities for corporations seeking low wage labor.

Contradictory things can be true--both x and not-x--especially at different times, or different states of system. This violates our sense of logic and invites idea of the absurd as reality--as though there were no reality, as though everything were a big joke, and everything is ironic, absurd. So some anthropologists cannot write without noting, “it is ironic to note that. . .”

This complex system with chaotic elements that sometimes seem random is the material basis of the post-modern ideology—especially the condemnations of science and denials of any possibility of reality-based knowledge (Kuznar 1997; Spiro 1992, 1993, 1996) . We can explain events after they happen in terms of system dynamics, but when the system is very complex, we cannot predict with any degree of accuracy. Thus it appears that events are unique, and this resonates with the hyper-relativism of postmodernism that maintains that cultures and events are unique (Spiro 1992). Because familiar linear logics are not predictive in complex system, some, who equate science with the understanding of linear processes, conclude that science is not applicable. I return to this theme at the end of the essay.

Processes of globalization affect all of our consciousnesses. Market women in Ghana, Yourba city dwellers in Nigeria, farm workers in Egypt and families in Oaxaca talk about and understand currency reform, negative growth, foreign exchange, and national economic crises (Winslow 1997). But the connections can be indirect. People of Belize have responded to such forces by creating a Belizean culture though it mis represents many economic relationships (Wilk 1997). Shrimpers in Mississippi and Alabama are aware of the impact of imported pond-raised shrimp on their livelihoods, but tend to think in terms of vague conspiracies rather than a global economic system (Durrenberger 1992, 1996).

It may be true, as Geertz (1973) suggested, that people are suspended in webs of meaning, but those webs are not always of their own making and are often irrelevant. To return to Malinowski, Steward, and Wolf, we ask what is the material base? What is the system and how does it work?

The global system is based on world wide instant communications--microchip and communications technology. We see the consequences most clearly in areas most linked with communication--media, entertainment, cultural productions, and finance. I think this is why when anthropologists turn to the global system, we usually discuss cultural productions. In the dazzle, economic and political relations recede into the dimness of the background. It is these I want to describe, not the dazzle. For this I have consulted a number of redundant works, and will not assess the virtues of each here or cite them individually since I have simply put together here ideas that are widely available in many sources[i]. Perhaps the most accessible of them is William Greider’s One World, Ready or Not.

Figure 1 illustrates the classic upward spiral of capitalist production that Eric Wolf discusses (1997). People invest capital in technology that increases productivity and thus create profits that they can use as capital to put back into the process. As the technology develops, it enlarges productive capacity and reduces costs and thus protects the producer’s share of the market. Those who control capital strive to produce as cheaply as possible so they can sell their product for a smaller price and control larger shares of the market. As their market share increases, producers enlarge productive capacity, and thus increase productivity to further enhance profits, which can re-enter the cycle.

As this process continues, higher producers use profits to increase demand by lowering prices. Thus, there are more profits, more capital, more efficient technology and higher productivity, more production, lower prices, and increased demand. Especially if labor is sufficiently organized to make collective claims, such benefits may be passed along as increased wages. Lower prices mean more buying power and greater consumption that fuels demand. The system spirals upward much in the way Marx envisioned in Capital.

/Figure 1 here/

But, the enlarged productive capacity results in surpluses that the producers cannot sell. This initiates the downward spiral that Figure 2 illustrates. Producers need to reduce costs, so they cut costs of labor by making greater investments in technology to increase productivity even more. They combine efforts with competitors for research and development. They begin to sell their plants, shrink middle management, convert permanent jobs to temporary ones, and contract out as many processes as they can. Katherine Newman’s ethnographic studies of unemployed middle-class workers (1988, 1993) have shown the results of these processes for white-collar and managerial workers.

/Figure 2 here/

Producers look for new markets where demand is greater than supply and relocate production in polities where they can gain political favors to control wages and taxes and to provide access to markets. Here, state policies may be more or less attractive to companies. Those states that practice Draconian control of labor and middle classes are more attractive (Wilsonl1992) as are those that offer concessions (Bonanno and Constance 1996)

Through these processes and through global auctions of capital, finance gains power over productive capital as Figure 3 illustrates. Financial decisions become more central, more important than productive ones to the point that the Wall Street Journal (November 8, 1999) can proclaim that “making things is out of fashion.” As productivity increases there is less return per unit manufactured, and thus less profit.

Those who gain capital in the global auctions must pay for it. The interest they pay for the use of capital reduces their profits. The reduction of profit leads to pressure to reduce wages, and to corporations borrowing more capital. The interest they pay on borrowed capital reduces profits, so there is a self-intensifying process of less profit, borrowing capital, paying interest, less profits.

At the same time, corporations enlarge productive capacity to increase productivity. This requires more capital, and increases the pressure to borrow capital and provides a second entrance to the same self-intensifying process. As these processes intensify, power shifts from corporate management to financiers who control the flow of funds to corporations and finance gains power over productive capital, the machines and plants that produce things. As an example, the percent of earnings for capital in the U.S. decreased from 34% in 1960 to 15% in 1990.

/Figure 3 here/

Financial value of corporations is determined by profits and debt repayment as well as accumulated savings as Figure 4 illustrates. To raise capital, there are global auctions for finance capital. The price of finance capital on these auctions is influenced by U.S. and European government debt, industrialization in emerging nations, the status of multinational firms, and the interrelationships of these variables. Thus, the financial value is un-coupled from productive capacity. As financial value is un-coupled from productive capacity, it no longer rests on transparent economic computations and projections. It becomes a semi-autonomous domain of myths, stories, symbols, fads, and other cultural constructs. As this process accelerates, financial value becomes less predictable and more quasi-random.

/Figure 4 here/

From the point of view of their home polities, corporations trade jobs for access to markets in other polities. But this allows corporations to diversify their manufacturing sites and isolate the total process from any local and regional fluctuations. The significant unit is the corporation, not any of the polities where its operations are based for the moment. Thus the corporation insulates itself from impacts of local events in any single polity. In response to an upheaval in Burma, for instance, a corporation may move its operation to Sri Lanka or Mexico or Israel.

One consequence of this process is to erode the manufacturing base of industrial lands. Another consequence is that the unit of production and consumption of raw materials and manufactured goods is the corporation that straddles a number of polities. The systemic connections, what economists call forward and backward linkages, are within the corporation, not within the polity (Wilson 1992). Thus as corporate economic systems are articulated and integrated, local, regional, and national economic systems are dis-articulated as Beckford (1972) pointed out in the Caribbean.

Wilson’s (1992) analysis of maquilador factories in Mexico shows how isolated multination assembly facilities are from the economies of the areas where they are located. At the same time they are important to the economy of the region because they provide jobs and income that people can spend for their subsistence. From the point of view of national or regional planning, however, the maquilador remains isolated from the rest of the economy. The linkages—supplies of components and markets for final products—are not in the region. If the enterprises are based on raw materials, bauxite and bananas, to use Beckford’s examples, then economic activity in those two sectors do not influence each other, there are no economic linkages, and the region’s economy is not articulated. He termed this process “dis-articulation.”

There are three major ways that polities can control their economic systems: fiscal policy (adopting or rejecting social programs that require government spending), tax policy, and monetary policy (interest rates). All of these have multiple determinants as figure 5 shows. The three policy processes are interest rates, social programs, and tax policy.

Social programs vary directly with taxes—more taxes, more programs; fewer programs, less taxes. But they have opposite consequences for demand for goods. The more social programs, the greater the demand; the more taxes, the less the demand. As demand increases, inflation increases when people bid up the prices of goods. But as demand increases, the number of jobs increases, and as the price of labor increases with the number of jobs, inflation increases.

As the number of jobs increases, demand increases because more workers and their families have more money to spend. As inflation increases, interest rates increase. As social programs increase beyond tax revenues, governments must borrow to support them, and this adds to inflationary pressure and increases interest rates. As interest rates increase, interest becomes a greater portion of the national budget and government borrowing increases. Increasing interest rates attract foreign lenders and suppliers of capital.

/Figure 5 here/

Figure 6 illustrates that the value of the currency increases in turn as foreign loans and capital increase. As the value of the currency increases, it is more attractive to foreign buyers and investors so interest rates increase. And as interest rates increase, the value of the currency increases. These variables mutually enhance one another. As currency value increases relative to others, export prices increase and import prices decrease. Thus there is less demand for exports and more demand for imports. Imports increase and exports decrease.

The trade deficit is a measure of the balance of imports and exports, so it increases as the price of exports increases (and income from them decreases as sales fall off) and decreases as the price of imports increases and there are fewer imports because people cannot afford them. As the prices of imports decrease, and people import more, the trade deficit increases, which decreases the value of the currency which in turn, increases the price of domestic goods and exports, and makes for fewer exports and a greater trade deficit.

/Figure 6 here/

Figure 7 indicates several interrelated self-intensifying processes that link trade deficits, relative prices of imports and exports, interest rates, inflation rates, foreign loans, government borrowing, social programs, tax rates, and jobs. The trade deficit is inversely related to the value of currency—the greater the deficit, the less the value of currency. The value of the currency is positively related to interest rates—the higher the value of the currency the higher the interest rates and the higher the interest rates, the higher the inflation rates. There is also a direct inverse relationship between currency value and inflation.

/Figure 7 here/

Though the concept is not familiar to Americans, as Hannerz (1996) points out, in many polities, the government derives its legitimacy from a sense of serving its citizens, a more or less implicit social contract. When people lose jobs, state policy provides for social programs to take up the slack, so as there are fewer jobs in such a polity, there is greater expenditure for social programs. The more social programs expend, the greater are taxes. Governments can also cover the cost of social programs by borrowing, a policy that increases inflation. The greater the cost of social programs, the greater the rate of inflation by virtue of both increased demand and increased government borrowing.

The more people have jobs, the more they create demand for products and bid up prices to create inflation. The more people have jobs, the more they pay in taxes. As government borrowing and inflation rates increase, interest rates increase. As interest rates increase, inflation increases.

These relationships show the interface of the political and the economic. Governments can attempt to control these variables by policies and institutional arrangements to control interest rates, expenditures for social programs, and taxes. But at the same time polities lose control of their own territorially based economic systems as the systemic connections are concentrated within multi-national corporations rather than polities.

Another source for the declining influence of some governments is international agencies that control the conditions for lending and the conditions for importing and exporting goods—trade arrangements. These agencies can and do set strict limits on the policies of governments in return for access to foreign capital (Hackenberg 1997, Greenberg 1997). A source of increasing power in other polities is their ability to set the conditions for the operation of international institutions such as the World Bank. Some (Bonanno and Constance 1996) suggest that all states lose power as these alternate institutions gain it.

Figure 8 summarizes the consequences of these interrelated processes. Among these I include irrelevance of government policy in “developing” lands, and if policy is irrelevant, who makes it and how they make it is irrelevant, so political processes are irrelevant whether they be participatory or not; whether they be democratic or not—does not matter. Other consequences are disarticulation of local economic systems, increased reliance on employment rather than household economies for subsistence and well being, increased unemployment, deterioration of well being, widening gap between rich and poor, deterioration of social contract, rise of populism, rise of localism and identity politics, ecological deterioration, disarticulation of the link between finance and production, and a quasi-random process in global financial markets.

/Figure 8 here/

As finance gains control over productive capital and as polities become more responsive to fiscal policy, finance gains control of both corporations and polities. Governments of countries that receive loans, of lands that receive industrial plants and other “development” thus become less important in the global scheme and less consequential in their own lands; even corporations become less influential, and flows of finance become more decisive. With this is an increasing importance of the institutions that control flows of finance such as the World Bank and the institutions that control the rules of international trade, GATT.

These systems are cultural artifacts that other more powerful national policies create. Different national accounting policies and practices make for different corporate behavior. Japanese corporations borrow from banks and therefore have long term profit horizons. U.S. firms raise capital on the stock market and have to pay dividends to keep value of stocks up so they can return to the same source for more capital. Thus, they have quarterly profit horizons, short by Japanese standards.

For all their talk of “the real world,” of “realism,” and “being hard-nosed,” financers are the shamans of the modern world. Sahlins’s (2000) label for the Kennedy administration’s outlook is appropriate here as well--“hard-headed surrealists”--because their “reality” is a network of bizarre cultural assemblages.

Money is a cultural artifact and financier-shamans are suspended in irreal webs of meaning, their heads in the cultural ozone, their feet dangling in the stratosphere, never treading the ground of productive relationships much less food production. Even so, international finance has far-reaching material consequences for instance, in setting relative values of currencies. It has the power to render fertile fields sterile and productive factories ghost structures, to move peasants into factories and factories to distant lands, to determine government polices and stay the hands of revolutionaries.

Ethnography cannot focus on a global system that has no place, no locale. In Chicago I talked to a financier whose project was to decide whether to buy certain notes for his firm. To do this, he had to assess real estate in the Rio Grande valley. Participant-observation doesn’t get us very far. We cannot go be financiers, or corporate executive officers or world leaders. If we did, we would buy into the system, and it would define our reality. We would not then question it.

We have to rely on ethnography which we can extend by surveys and comparative work to gain an appreciation for the range of cultural constructs. For some questions we have to use other sources such as the Wall Street Journal and Forbes as C. Wright Mills did in the 1960's. We can expand this coverage by looking at corporate reports and the internet. We can piece together ethnographies of many places to see patterns and keep one eye on the local, where we can see clearly empirical details working out day by day as Malinowski and Boas did, but we enlarge the view as Steward did until it is global scope as Wolf’s work was .

Does this mean we should close up our anthropological shop and send our graduate students to business schools? No, no more than we send our students to seminaries to understand priesthoods. The business schools are the seminaries of the new religion of finance. It is always good to have an inside view. But we should follow the wisdom of Malinowski and develop the external view as well.

We should remember as Alf Hornborg (2001) argues, that money is a part of a reality that conceals social facts. Our tacit agreement to grant such categories epistemological power by granting them ontological reality gives them reality in the sense that we all participate in our cultures. The agreement of Inca peasants, if we can call it agreement, to grant their emperor superhuman status gave him power. Though it derives from cultural symbols, that power is as real and as great for modern financers as it was for Inca. But, as Wolf argued, the symbols of Inca and financier alike are rooted in relations of power. They don’t descend from the ozone to the earth. That’s why it’s reasonable to question whether any but the ruling classes have choices to exercise.

The challenge of anthropology is to be able to see beyond such folk models to the underlying social relationships that organize productive processes and to understand the consequences of different understandings of reality for action. We need to understand the consequences of different actions on social relations of production and the social and natural environments. We cannot understand the myth if we buy into it. If we repeat it, it simply seems natural—as natural as markets and money to financers and as their gods were to Inca.

Consequences

All who are interested in the production and provisioning of food have struggled with the relative importance of local ecological factors, organizational proclivities, markets, administrations and larger political and economic forces. As anthropologists and others committed to the ground-truth-testing of ethnography encounter the reverberations of globalization in the locales where we work, we can either retreat into a romantic localism or contend with the realities as they present themselves to us and the people we are trying to understand. We anthropologists have just recently acknowledged that nations and states are important and tried to conceptualize them and now, like the people we try to understand, we are flung into the chaos of global relations. Apostle et al. (1998) compare historical backgrounds and structural necessities that underlie the similarities and differences between Norway and Atlantic Canada.

They argue that community is the realm of interpersonal ties and egalitarian social networks characterized by multiple overlapping identities and complex relationships. State is the sphere of policy, law and government distinguished by hierarchic and bureaucratic relationships of authority that are professional and one-dimensional. The market--the area of competition, economic efficiency, and rationality--is decentralized and egalitarian typified by fleeting, impersonal, task-oriented social relationships that lack inherent value. Globalization, they argue, is the process of the expansion of the market and the contraction of the state.

They show how globalization dis-articulates local economic systems. Canadian policy caused fisheries to bifurcate into an inshore fishery dependent on household welfare payments and a vertically integrated industrial offshore fishery supported by corporate welfare payments. In Norway, policy supported fisher organizations and influence in policy making, so household production persisted. Threats to the resource on both sides of the Atlantic ushered in two decades of fisheries management of the 70s which gave way in the 90s to the forces of globalization.

Apostle and his colleagues leave no doubt that the different policies and political climates determine different histories that determine the different outcomes. Emphasis on local or even regional ecologies would be misleading. In the Canadian Maritimes local factors helped buffer fisheries against economic depression and provided alternatives and barriers to organization. In Newfoundland, where occupational alternatives and conflicts of scheduling between fishing and farming work thwarted organization, the Fisherman’s Protective Union failed after it evolved into a commercial empire with no member participation. In Norway, fewer alternatives, emphasis on full time fishing, and the decentralization of power along with a different political and policy climate almost demanded that fishers organize.

Paradoxically, the federal system of Canada, with power anchored in the constitution, allows for more centralized control than the unitary state of Norway in which interested groups work closely with government officials. In Norway, fishers exert influence through their associations; in Canada with its fragmented fishers, there is little consensus or mobilization of common interest to contest centralized decision-making (Apostle et al. 1998: 200).

Corporate welfare has encouraged the development of large-scale harvesting and processing capacity in both Canada and Norway. When corporations get into trouble they have sufficient political clout to persuade politicians to rescue them. Thus, in spite of mighty propaganda that preaches that markets determine all, these firms are not exposed to the rigors of the marketplace.

The global economy dis-articulates coastal communities and economic systems. Privatization has become a policy catchword. Whereas individual quotas may solve short-term problems of too many boats chasing too few fish they are also associated with increased economic and social stratification. With the withdrawal of the state, fewer resources are available to fishing communities. All in all, “The breakdown in the relationships tying state, market, and coastal communities together point towards social and ecological disintegration” (Apostle et al. 1998:338).

The powerful conclusions of this collaborative work are that because they are marginalized by market forces or fisheries management decisions, the viability of coastal communities and fishing as a way of life is threatened (Apostle et al. 1998:341). The market is not a politically neutral institution but a socially constructed, politically maintained institution functioning according to rules that reflect culturally specific values (Apostle et al. 1998:342).

Greenberg (1997) shows that we cannot expect uniform effects of these processes. For instance, Structural Adjustment Programs may set prices for imports, but the administrative levels between the state and the locale may not insure that middlemen in regional marketing systems pass them on to farmers. Even if policies have negative impacts on households, it doesn’t follow that they are ecologically deleterious. If the policies force marginal smallholders to abandon farming it may aid environmental recovery.

Different rural producers have different endowments of land and capital and differential access to labor because of variability of household formations. Structural Adjustment Programs may push some households toward unsustainable uses of their environments, and others into diversification with lower risk activities with greater potential returns. Only quantitative local studies can provide this kind of information, and there have not been many of those (Greenberg 1997).

Thus for all their differences of outlook and emphasis both Eric Wolf (1997) and Marshall Sahlins (2000) urge ethnographic understanding of global systems. Sahlins is intent to show that the West did not simply dominate the Rest with the onslaught of capitalism, but that each locale, each people, responded according to their own lights. The Europeans provided the means to achieve locally meaningful cultural goals. Surfing the global economy in service of their own cultural aspirations, peasant and tribal people created new synthetic formations that Western social scientists, he argues, did not recognize. Western researchers saw urbanization, migration, remittance dependency, labor recruitment, ethnic formation and not the translocal cultural whole (2000:522).

We can get a sense of the variability of responses by comparing Venezuela and Sweden from the work of Monica Lindh de Montoya and Miguel Montoya (in press). The wealth of Sweden is based on manufacturing while Venezuela’s is from oil. Sweden’s revenues depend on taxation while Venezuela’s depend on the world market for oil.

What hurts the Swedish economy is plants relocating to areas of cheap labor and eroding the employment opportunities for Swedish workers as well as the tax base of the polity. What threatens Venezuela is dips in the world price of oil. Sweden, however, has maintained its social services while Venezuela has had to have recourse to government borrowing and IMF mandated reforms.

In Sweden there has been no upheaval while in Venezuela a populist president has been elected. In Sweden savings are freed for investment while they are not in Venezuela. Under Swedish law, corporations in Sweden must be transparent. Venezuelan firms can be as opaque as their managements or owners want. Thus half the people in Sweden are investors while only 5% of Venezuelans are.

When Volvo threatened to move its facilities from Sweden, investors could have an impact on the decision while investors can have no impact on Venezuelan corporate decisions. In Sweden there is a tradition of ethical investing in line with the notion of social contracts among workers, government, and firms while there is no such notion in Venezuela.

So while it is true that different locales, even different households respond differently, they are responding to similar forces, and it behooves us to take the step beyond the local to understand those forces as a system so that we can better appreciate the variety of local responses.

When we do this, we see that the spread of market isn't autonomous or natural, but consequence of state policies to allow these developments. State policies are at the foundation of globalization processes. But in this all states are not equal. The policies that count are those of the participants in the Breton Woods agreements that established the World Bank and the current system of world trade. Other polities lose influence even over their own economic systems as they become disarticulated and as their governments are controlled by IMF Structural Adjustment Program policies. As the local governments lose their influence, so political processes become irrelevant. As local governments break the social contract with their people, the people respond with fundamentalist, separatist, and populist political manifestations to rectify their situations.

As the populations of First World nations take refuge in media formed escapes, as educational policies inculcate historical amnesia, as people increasingly believe that markets are natural forces and business does only what it must, the people of the first world are surprised when these processes in distant lands reverberate upon them personally. Then governments seize on this response to amplify the sense of amnesia and separation by quasi-religious rhetorics of combating evil in the world to protect their citizens. This reminds one at once of Jules Henry’s (1963) conclusion that American education made students stupid and Marvin Harris’s(1974) that witchcraft in medieval Europe was used by the ruling classes of Europe to control alienated citizens by promising to protect them from this source of evil.

The states that establish the rules of globalization serve the interests of corporations--but at the same time, they bring governments into confrontation with their inability to serve public interest—to protect environments or to insure economic welfare of people--and this causes tensions in democracies—those states in which governments have to be elected. There is a tension between the interests of corporations and interests of populations. That's what we see playing out in process of globalization as numbers of people gather from around the world to protest where ever international bodies meet to discuss policies of world trade. If we want to understand these movements and their manifestations from protest to suicidal attacks, we must understand the systems that gives rise to them.

A return to anthropological theory

This we cannot do by the appeal to irony, illogic, or hyper-relativism of postmodernism. It is not just another joke. The criterion of understanding is not whether one “gets it” or not (Durrenberger and Tannenbaum 2002). Postmodernism in this context becomes another obscurantist ideology in service of the powerful (Durrenberger 1995b).

Salmon (2001) sees postmodernism as more than a distrust of grand theory and emphasis on the local. After all, reflexivity and an explicitly interpertivist stance also characterize Malinowski. Melford Spiro (1993) summed it up when he said that what is new about postmodernism is not true and what is true about postmodernism is not new. In conversation, Laura Nader commented that the problem with postmodernists is they don’t know much about anthropology. In addition postmodernism challenges the assumption that it is possible to describe other cultures and supposes that such descriptions must necessarily misrepresent and disrespect them (Barrett 1996).

While one may accept the classic points of view that people continually involved in self-construction embedded in standpoints derived from social relations and identities, that knowledge is historically contingent and shaped by values and interests, that people negotiate meanings, and that historical experiences and social locations shape identities, it remains true, as Alford (1998:3) observed that, “The postmodern critique of the orthodox conception of scientific method offers us few clues about how to do our work.”

To be sure science is the fuel of globalization from the atomic bomb to the microchip; from the steamship to the telegraph; from the railroad surveyor to the rocket scientist placing communications satellites our missile platforms in orbit. Some conclude that science must thus must be ethically bad, a tool of hierarchy. May be. But the same could be said of religion if we put all religion in one category. We know that science, like religion is variable and can serve different interests from warlike to peaceful. Science can serve one person’s or culture’s concept of the just or the unjust

The vast variability within single religious traditions from reactionary misogyny to liberation theology should make us cautious about sweeping statements about religion and religions. And so for science. Like religion, science can be put to variable purposes and those with anti-scientific agendas should guard against condemning a way of knowing by the uses of its knowledge.

Tom King and I concluded our introductory comments to our book on fisheries management (2000:15) by suggesting that there is no general relationship between policy and practice. We argued “that abstract theoretical constructs are likely to be misleading rather than enlightening.” This means that “adaptability and long-term system viability are likely to be local and not generalizable.” Because we reject grand theory does not mean we reject ethnography. On the contrary we hold, as I do in this paper, that ethnography is the only way we can understand the on the ground realities of polices or of global systems.

But we need to situate our ethnographies in terms of what we know of those larger systems. My concluding point, then, is not the abdication science and ethnography of postmodernism, understandable as that might be, but rather a call for more and better ethnography and more and more powerful scientific understandings of humanity.

References Cited

Alford, Robert R.

1998. The Craft of Inquiry: Theories, Methods, Evidence. New York: Oxford

University Press.

Anderson, Benedict R.

1991 [1983] Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origin and Spread of Nationalism. Revised Ed. London: Verso.

Apostle, Richard, Gene Barrett, Petter Holm, Svein Jentoft, Leigh Mazany, Bonnie McCay, and Knut Mikalsen.

1998. Community, State, and Market on the North Atlantic Rim: Challenges to Modernity in the Fisheries. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

Appadurai, Arjun

1996. Modernity at Large: Cultural Dimensions of Globalization. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

Appleby, Gordon

1985 Marketplace Development in the Gambia River Basin. IN

Markets and marketing. Monographs in Economic Anthropology, No. 4

Stuart Plattner, editor. Pages 79-97 .Lanham, MD: University Press of

America.

Athanasiou, Tom

1996. Divided Planet: The Ecology of Rich and Poor. New York: Little, Brown

and Company.

Barboza, David

2000 Goliath of the Hog World: Fast Rise of Smithfield Foods Makes Regulators Wary. New York Times. April 7,2000. Business Section p. 1.

Barnet, Richard J. and John Cavanagh

1994 Global Dreams: Imperial Corporations and The New World Order. New York: Simon And Schuster.

Barrett, Stanley R.

1996. Anthropology: A Student’s Guide to Theory and Method. Toronto:

University of Toronto Press.

Barth, Fredrik

1956. Ecologic Relationships of Ethnic Groups in Swat, North Pakistan.

American Anthropologist 58: 1079-1089.

Beckford, George L.

1972 Persistent Poverty: Underdevelopment in Plantation Economies of the Third World. New york: Oxford University Press.

Blanton, Richard E. and Peter N. Peregrine

1997. Main Assumptions and Variables for Economic Analysis Beyond the Local System. IN Economic Analysis Beyond the Local Systems, Richard E. Blanton, Peter N. Peregrine, Deborah Winslow, and Thomas D. Hall, editors. Monographs in Economic Anthropology No. 13. Lanham. University Press of America. Pages 3-12.

Bonanno, Alessandro and Douglas Constance

1996. Caught in the Net: The Global Tuna Industry, Environmentalists, and the

State. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.

Comaroff, John and Jean Comaroff

1992. Ethnography and the Historical Imagination. Boulder: Westview.

Durrenberger, E. Paul

1992. It’s All Politics: South Alabama's Seafood Industry. University of Illinois Press.

1995a Icelandic Essays: Explorations in the Anthropology of a Modern

Nation. San Francisco, Rudi Press.

1995b Postmodern Anthropology, Science, and Humanism. Review of

Anthropological Other or Burmese Brother: Studies in Cultural analysis

by Melford Spiro. Anthropology and Humanism 20:(1):88-90.

1996 Gulf Coast Soundings: People and Policy in the Mississippi Shrimp Industry. University Press of Kansas.

1997. That'll Teach You: Cognition and Practice in a Union Local. Human Organization. 56(4):388-392.

Durrenberger, E. Paul and Nicola Tannenbaum

2002. Chayanov and Theory in Economic Anthropology. IN Theory in Economic

Anthropology. Walnut Creek, CA. Altamira. Pages 137-153.

Durrenberger, E. Paul and Gísli Pálsson

1996 Introduction. IN Images of Contemporary Iceland: Everyday Lives and Global Contexts. E. Paul Durrenberger and Gísli Pálsson, editors. Iowa City: University of Iowa Press. Pages 1-22.

Durrenberger, E. Paul and Suzan Erem

1997a Getting a Raise: Organizing Workers in an Industrializing Hospital. Journal of Anthropological Research 53(1):31-46.

1997b The Dance of Power: Ritual and Agency among Unionized American Health Care Workers. American Anthropologist 99 (3):489-495.

1999a The Abstract, the Concrete, the Political, and the Academic: Anthropology and a Labor Union in the United States. Human Organization 58(3):305-312.

1999b The Weak Suffer What They Must: A Natural Experiment in Thought and Structure. American Anthropologist 101 (4):783-793.

2000 When Anthropology Fails: Stories from the Ethnographic Front. Anthropology and Humanism 25 (1):50-63

Durrenberger, E. Paul and Kendall Thu

1994a North Carolina's Hog Industry: The Rest of the Story. Culture and Agriculture 49 (Spring 1994):21-23.

1994b Our Changing Swine Industry and Signals of Discontent. Iowa Groundwater Quarterly. 5 (4):5-7.

1996a The Industrialization of Swine Production in the U.S.: An Overview. Culture and Agriculture 18 (1):19-22.

1996b The Expansion of Large Scale Hog Farming in Iowa: The Applicability of Goldschmidt's Findings Fifty Years Later. Human Organization. 55 (4):409-415.

1997a Introduction. IN Pigs, Profits, and Rural Communities. State University of New York Press.

1997b Signals, Systems, and Environment in Industrial Food Systems. Journal of Political Ecology 4:27-38.

Durrenberger, E. Paul and John Morrison

1979. Comments on Brown’s ethnoscience. American Ethnologist 6 (2): 408-

409.

Eckstein, Susan, Editor

1989. Power and Popular Protest: Latin American Social Movements. Berkeley: University of California Press.

Gottschalk, Marie

1998. The Shadow Welfare State: Labor, Business, and the Politics of Health

Care in the United States. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Greenberg, James B.

1997. Political Ecology of Structural-Adjustment Policies: The Case of the Dominican Republic. Culture and Agriculture 19 (3):85-93.

Greenwood, D.J.

1973. The Political Economy of Peasant Family Farming: Some Anthropological

Perspectives on Rationality and Adaptation. Rural Development

Occasional Paper No. 2. Rural Development Committee, Center for

International Studies: Cornell University.

Greider, William

1998. One World, Ready or Not: The Manic Logic of Global Capitalism. New York: Simon and Schuster.

Hackenberg, Robert A.

1997 Rural Development in the Global Village: l An Oppositional Political Ecology? Culture and Agriculture 19(3): 71-78.

Hadden, Jeffrey K. and Anson Shupe

1989 Secularization and Fundamentalism Reconsidered Vol III. Religion and The Political Order. New York: Paragon.

Hanks, Lucian

1972 Rice and Man: Agricultural Ecology in Southeast Asia. Arlington Heights, Ill: AHM Publishing Corporation.

Hannerz, Ulf

1996. Transnational Connections: Culture, People, Places. New York:

Routledge.

Harris, Marvin

1974. Cows, Pigs, Wars, and Witches: The Riddles of Culture. New York:

Vintage Books.

Henry, Jules

1963 Culture Against Man. New York: Random House.

Herzfeld, Michael

1993 The Social Production of Indifference Exploring the Symbolic Roots of

Western Bureaucracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Hobsbawm, Eric and Terrance Ranger

1983. The Invention of Tradition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Hornborg, Alf

2001. Power of the Machine: Money, Modernity, and Global Ecology.

Walnut Creek, CA: Altamira Press.

Ingold, Tim

1993 The Art of Translation in a Continuous World. IN Beyond Boundaries: Understanding, Translation and Anthropological Discourse. Gísli Pálsson, editor. Providence: Berg. Pages 210-230.

Keesing, Roger

1972. Paradigms lost: The new ethnography and the new linguistics.

Southwestern Journal of Anthropology 28:299-332.

King, Thomas D. and E. Paul Durrenberger

1999. Introduction. IN State and Community in Fisheries management: Power,

Policy and Practice. E. Paul Durrenberger and Thomas D. King, editors.

Westport, Connecticut: Bergin and Garvey. Pages 1-15.

Klitgaard, Robert

1990 Tropical Gangsters: One man’s Experience With Development and Decadence in Deepest Africa. New York: Basic Books.

Lave, Jean

1988. Cognition in Practice: Mind, mathematics and Culture in Everyday Life.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Leach, Edmund R.

1954. Political Systems of Highland Burma. Boston. Beacon.

Longworth, Richard C.

1998 Global Squeeze: The Coming Crisis for First-World Nations. Chicago: Contemporary Books.

Malinowski, B.

1922. Argonauts of the Western Pacific. Prospect Heights. Waveland.

Mills, C. Wright

1956 The Power Elite. New York: Oxford University Press.

Mintz, Sidney W.

2002. Sweetness and Power: The Place of Sugar in Modern History. New York: Penguin.

Montoya, Miguel

In press Emerging markets, Globalization and The Small Investor: The Case of Venezuela. IN Development Beyond the 20th Century: A critical Discussion in Economic Anthropology. Jeffery Cohen and Norbert Dannhauser, eds. Walnut Creek, Ca: Altamira.

Montoya, Monica Lindh de

In press. Looking into the future: Anthropology and Financial Markets. IN Development Beyond the 20th Century: A critical Discussion in Economic Anthropology. Jeffery Cohen and Norbert Dannhauser, eds. Walnut Creek, Ca: Altamira.

Murphy, Robert and Julian H. Steward

1956. Tappers and Trappers: Parallel Process in Acculturation. Reprinted IN Robert A. Manners and David Kaplan, editors, Theory in Anthropology: A Sourcebook. Chicago: Aldine. Pages393-408.

Ohmae, Kenichi

1995 The End of the Nation state: The Rise of Regional Economies: How Capital, Corporations, Consumers and Communication are Reshaping Global Markets. New York: The Free Press.

Salzmlan, Philip Carl

2000. Understanding Culture: An Introduction to Anthropological Theory.

Prospect Heights, Illinois: Waveland.

Scott, James

1985 Weapons of the Weak. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Skinner, G. William

1964. Marketing and Social Structure in rural China (Part 1) Journal of Asian

Studies 14 (1):3-43.

1977. Cities and the Hierarchy of Local Systems. IN The City in Late Imperial

China. G. William Skinner, editor: pgs 273-351. Stanford: Stanford

University Press.

Small, David and Nicola Tannenbaum

2001. At the Interface: The Household and Beyond: Some Conclusions. IN At

the Interface: The Household and Beyond. Monographs in Economic

Anthropology No. 15. David B. Small and Nicola Tannenbaum, editors.

Pages 221-232. Lanham, MD: University Press of America.

Smallwood, Lola

1999 With Fur Demand Down, Raccoons Thriving. Chicago Tribune. Sunday July 11, 1999 Section 1 page 1.

Smith, Carol A.

1984. Local History in Global Context: Social and Economic Transitions in

Western Guatemala. Comparative Studies in Society and History 26

(2):193-228.

1985. How to Count Onions: Methods for a Regional Analysis of Marketing. IN

Markets and marketing. Monographs in Economic Anthropology, No. 4

Stuart Plattner, editor. Pages 49-77.Lanham, MD: University Press of

America.

Spero, Joan Edelman

1989. The Politics of International Economic Relations. Fourth Edition. New York: St. Martins.

Spiro, Melford

1992. Anthropological Other or Burmese Brother: Studies in Cultural Analysis.

New Brunswick. Transaction Publishers.

1993. What is New About “Postmodern Subjectivity?” Paper presented to the

American Anthropological Association.

1996. Postmodernist Anthropology, Subjectivity, and Science: A Modernist

Critique. Comparative Studies of Society and History. 38(4):759-780.

Steward, Julian

1963. Foreword. IN F.K. Lehman. The Structure of Chin Society: A Tribal People of Burma Adapted to a non-Western Civilization. Urbana. University of Illinois Press.

Wallace, Anthony F.C.

1961. Culture and Personality. New York: Random House.

Wilson, Patricia A.

1992. Exports and Local Development: Mexico’s New Maquiladoras. Austin:

University of Texas Press.

Winslow Deborah

1997 Anthropology and Structural Adjustment Programs. IN Economic Analysis Beyond the Local Systems, Richard E. Blanton, Peter N. Peregrine, Deborah Winslow, and Thomas D. Hall, editors. Monographs in Economic Anthropology No. 13. Lanham. University Press of America. Pages 197-208.

Wilk, Richard R.

1997 Emerging Linkages in the World System and The Challenge to Economic Anthropology. IN Economic Analysis Beyond the Local Systems, Richard E. Blanton, Peter N. Peregrine, Deborah Winslow, and Thomas D. Hall, editors. Monographs in Economic Anthropology No. 13. Lanham. University Press of America. Pages 97-108.

Wolf, Eric

1957 Closed Corporate Peasant Communities in Mesoamerica and Central Java. Southwestern Journal of Anthropology 13(1):1-14.

1997 Europe and the People Without History. Berkeley: University of California Press.

1999 Envisioning Power: Ideologies of Dominance and Crisis. Berkeley: University of California Press.

FIGURE 1: CLASSIC UPWARD SPIRAL

FIGURE 2: DOWNWARD SPIRAL

% OF EARNINGS FOR

CAPITAL

1960=34%

1990=15%

FIGURE 3: HOW FINANCE GAINS POWER OVER

PRODUCTIVE CAPITAL

+

+

+

+

FIGURE 4: DETERMINANTS OF FINANCIAL VALUE

+

+

+

+

+

+

+ -

+

-

+

+

+ -

+ +

FIGURE 5: WAYS TO CONTROL A NATIONAL ECONOMY

FIGURE 6: FINANCIAL INFLUENCES ON IMPORTS AND EXPORTS

FIGURE 7: HOW POLICY LINKS WITH EXPORTS THROUG CURRANCY VALUE

• IRRELEVANCE OF GOVERNMENT POLICY

• IRRELEVANCE OF POLITICAL PROCESSES

• DISARTICULATION OF LOCAL ECONOMIC SYSTEMS

• INCREASED RELIANCE ON EMPLOYMENT VS. HOUSEHOLD ECONOMIES

• INCREASED UNEMPLOYMENT

• WIDENING GAP BETWEEN RICH AND POOR

• DETERIORATION OF SOCIAL CONTRACT

• RISE OF POPULISM

• RISE OF LOCALISM/IDENTITY POLITICS

• ECOLOTICAL DETERIORATION

• DISARTICULATION OF FINANCE AND PRODUCTION

• QUASI-RANDOM PROCESSES IN GLOBAL FINANCE

FIGURE 8: CONSEQUENCES

-----------------------

[i] The sources I have consulted include Eckstein 1989, Barner and Cavanagh 1994, Klitgaard 1990, Hadden and Shupe 1989, Longworth 1998, Greider 1997, Spero 1990, Ohmae 1995 and Athanasiou 1996.

-----------------------

FOREIGN LOANS & CAPITAL

INTEREST RATES

CURRENCY VALUE

INTEREST RATES

FOREIGN LOANS & CAPITAL

GVT BORROWING

INTEREST AS % OF NTL BUDGET

SOCIAL PROGRAMS

INFLATION

DEMAND

JOBS

TAXES

INCREASE DEMAND

CREATE CAPITAL

LOWER PRICES

INCREASE WAGES

PROFITS

PRODUCTIVITY

TECHNOLOGY

REDUCE COSTS

PROTECT MARKET SHARE

ENLARGE PRODUCTIVE

CAPACITY

CUT LABOR COSTS

SURPLUS SUPPLY

FIND NEW MARKETS

PRODUCTIVITY

TECHNOLOGY

PROFITS

REDUCE COSTS

ENLARGE PRODUCTIVE

CAPACITY

PROTECT MARKET SHARE

NEED TO REDUCE COSTS

SELL PLANTS

SHRINK MIDDLE MANAGEMENT

CONVERT JOBS TO TEMPS

CONTRACT OUT

RELOCATE IN POLITY

WITH POLITICAL FAVORS TO CONTROL WAGES, TAXES AND

PROVIDE MARKETS

JOIN /COMPETITORS

FOR R&D

GLOBAL AUCTIONS FOR FINANCE CAPITAL FOR

1. U.S. AND EUROPEAN GOVERNMENT DEBT

2. INDUSTRIALIZATION IN EMERGING NATIONS

3. MULTINATION FIRMS

DEBT REPAYMENT

ACCUMULATED SAVINGS

FINANCIAL VALUE

PROFIT

PRODUCTIVITY

LESS RETURN/UNIT

LESS PROFIT

ENLARGE PRODUCTIVE CAPACITY

MORE CAPITAL REQUIRED

BORROW CAPITAL

PAY INTEREST

PRESSURE TO RECUCE COSTS

POWER SHIFTS FROM

CORPORATE MANAGEMENT

TO FINANCIERS

LOWER WAGES

FEWER JOBS

LESS DEMAND

SOCIAL AND POLITICAL PROBLEMS

TRADE DEFICIT

IMPORTS

EXPORTS

IMPORT PRICES

EXPORT PRICES

CURRENCY VALUE

................
................

In order to avoid copyright disputes, this page is only a partial summary.

Google Online Preview   Download